The Quality of Life
Étonnant !
Ces gens boivent le café
dans des gobelets en carton
Baissent-ils encore leur
pantalon pour chier ?
(En Irak, ils n’ont même pas
le temps)
http://econo.free.fr/scripts/notes2.php3?codenote=158 http://www.reason.com/news/show/28243.html Post-Scarcity Prophet
Economist Paul Romer on growth, technological
change, and an unlimited human future. “One of the 25 most influential Americans,”
pronounced Time. “His ideas may just revolutionize the study of economics.”
Newsweek included him in its roster of “The Century Club,” a “list of
100 people for the New Century.” He is a perennial short-lister for the
Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics. His work has been lauded by business guru
Peter Drucker and Nobel-winning economist Robert Solow. He is the STANCO 25
Professor of Economics at Stanford University’s Graduate School of Business
and a senior fellow of the Hoover Institution. He was recently elected a
fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences. As one of the chief architects of “New Growth
Theory,” Paul Romer has had a massive and profound impact on modern economic
thinking and policymaking. New Growth Theory shows that economic growth
doesn’t arise just from adding more labor to more capital, but from new and
better ideas expressed as technological progress. Along the way, it
transforms economics from a “dismal science” that describes a world of
scarcity and diminishing returns into a discipline that reveals a path toward
constant improvement and unlimited potential. Ideas, in Romer’s formulation,
really do have consequences. Big ones. Before New Growth Theory, economists recognized
that technology contributed substantially to growth, but they couldn’t figure
out how to incorporate that insight into economic theory. Romer’s innovation,
expressed in technical articles with titles such as “Increasing Returns and
Long-Run Growth” and “Endogenous Technological Change,” has been to find ways
to describe rigorously and exactly how technological progress brings about
economic growth. As Robert Solow told Wired in 1996, “Paul single-handedly
turned [the study of economic growth] into a hot subject.” The 46-year-old Romer, son of former Colorado Gov.
Roy Romer, received his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Chicago in
1983, six years after earning a B.S. in physics at the same school. Before
joining Stanford’s faculty in 1996, he taught at a number of schools,
including the University of Chicago, the University of Rochester, and the
University of California at Berkeley. He and his wife, Virginia Langmuir, a
medical doctor, live in Portola Valley, California, and have two children. In June, reason Science Correspondent Ronald
Bailey interviewed Romer poolside at his house, which overlooks a huge
expanse of rolling ranchland owned by Stanford University. For more
information on Romer’s theories, turn to his Web site, www.stanford.edu/~promer/index.html. * * * reason: In terms of real per
capita income, Americans today are seven times richer than they were in 1900.
How did that happen? Paul Romer: Many things contributed,
but the essential one is technological change. What I mean by that is the
discovery of better ways to do things. In most coffee shops these days, you’ll find that the
small, medium, and large coffee cups all use the same size lid now, whereas
even five years ago they used to have different size lids for the different
cups. That small change in the geometry of the cups means that
somebody can save a little time in setting up the coffee shop, preparing the
cups, getting your coffee, and getting out. Millions of little discoveries
like that, combined with some very big discoveries, like the electric motor
and antibiotics, have made the
quality of life for people today dramatically higher than it was 100
years ago. The estimate you cite of a seven-fold increase in
income — that’s the kind of number you get from the official statistics, but
the truth is that if you look at the actual change in the quality of life,
it’s larger than the number suggests. People who had today’s average income
in 1900 were not as well off {aisés}
as the average person today, because they didn’t have access to cheap lattés {the stereotypical yuppie drink
(Wikipédia). Le “e” accentué est une frenchization de l’italien latte par certains américains alors que les français
écrivent latte et prononcent latté. En français, latté désigne le bois latté-collé. Le
laté est aussi une boisson d’Amérique du sud, me semble-t-il} or antibiotics or penicillin {Dr Destouche :
avant la pénicilline, la médecine ne guérissait rien}. reason: New Growth Theory divides
the world into “ideas” and “things.” What do you mean by that? Romer: The paper that
makes up the cup in the coffee shop is a thing. The
insight that you could design small, medium, and large cups so that they all
use the same size lid — that’s an idea. The critical difference is that only one person can use
a given amount of paper. Ideas can be used by many people at the same time. reason: What about human capital, the
acquired skills and learned abilities that can increase productivity? Romer: Human capital is
comparable to a thing. You have skills as a
writer, for example, and somebody — reason — can use those skills. That’s not
something that we can clone and replicate. The formula for an AIDS drug,
that’s something you could send over the Internet
or put on paper,
and then everybody in the world could have access to it. This is a hard distinction for people to get used
to, because there are so many tight interactions between human capital and
ideas. For example, human capital is how we make ideas. It takes people,
people’s brains, inquisitive people, to go out and find ideas like new drugs
for AIDS. Similarly, when
we make human capital with kids in school, we use ideas like the
Pythagorean theorem or the quadratic formula. So human capital makes ideas,
and ideas help make human capital. But still, they’re conceptually distinct. reason: What do you see as the
necessary preconditions for technological progress and economic growth? Romer: One extremely important
insight is that the process of technological discovery is supported by a
unique set of institutions. Those are most productive when they’re tightly
coupled with the institutions of the market. The Soviet Union had very strong
science in some fields, but it wasn’t coupled with strong institutions in the
market. The upshot was that the benefits of discovery were very limited for
people living there. The
wonder of the United States is that we’ve created institutions of
science and institutions of the market. They’re very different, but together
they’ve generated fantastic benefits. When we speak of institutions, economists mean
more than just organizations. We mean conventions, even rules, about how things are done.
The understanding which most sharply distinguishes science from the market
has to do with property rights. In the market, the fundamental institution is
the notion of private ownership, that an individual owns a piece of land or a
body of water or a barrel of oil and that individual has almost unlimited
scope to decide how that resource should be used. In science we have a very different ethic. When
somebody discovers something like the quadratic formula or the Pythagorean
theorem, the convention
in science is that he can’t control that idea. He has to give it away. He
publishes it. What’s rewarded in science is dissemination of ideas. And the
way we reward it is we give the most prestige and respect to those people who
first publish an idea. reason: Yet there is a mechanism
in the market called patents and copyright, for quasi-property rights in
ideas. Romer: That’s central to the
theory. To the extent that you’re using the market system to refine and bring
ideas into practical
application, we have to create some kind of control over the idea.
That could be through patents. It could be through copyright. It might even
be through secrecy. A firm can keep secret a lot of what it knows how to do. reason: A formula for Coca-Cola? Romer: Yes. Or take a lot of the
things that Wal-Mart understands about discount retailing. They have a lot of
insight about logistics and marketing which they haven’t patented or
copyrighted, yet they can still make more money on it than other people
because they keep it closely held within the firm. So for relying on the
market — and we do have to rely on the market to develop a lot of ideas — you
have to have some mechanisms of control and some opportunities for people to
make a profit developing those ideas. But there are other stages in the development of
ideas. Think about the basic science that led to the discovery of the
structure of DNA. There are some kinds of ideas where, once those ideas are
uncovered, you’d like to make them as broadly available as possible, so
everybody in the world can put them to good use. There we find it efficient
to give those ideas away for free and encourage everybody to use them. If
you’re going to be giving things away for free, you’re going to have to find
some system to finance them, and that’s where government support typically comes in. In the next century we’re going to be moving back
and forth, experimenting with where to draw the line between institutions of
science and institutions of the market. People used to assign different types
of problems to each institution. “Basic research” got government support; for
“applied product development,” we’d rely on the market. Over time, people
have recognized that that’s a pretty artificial distinction. What’s becoming
more clear is that it’s actually the combined energies of those two sets of
institutions, often working on the same problem, that lead to the best
outcomes. reason: We hear a lot of
complaints from academicians about how business and corporations are taking
over university research. Romer: I think it’s important to
have a distinct realm of science and a distinct realm of the market, but it’s
also very good to have interaction between those two. One of the best forms
of interaction is for people who work in one to move into the other. The people in university biology or biochemistry
departments complain when they see somebody go on leave from the university
and start a company that’s going to develop a new drug. That’s not the way it
was done 30 years ago. But this is the best way to take those freely
floating, contentiously discussed ideas from the realm of science and then
get them out into the market process, because the reality is that there are virtually
no ideas which generate
benefits for consumers if there’s not an intervening for-profit firm
which commercializes them, tailors them to the market, and then delivers
them. You can point to examples where things jump right from science to
benefits for the consumer, but that’s the exception, not the rule. reason: Do we run the risk of
ruining science by involving it too much in the market? Romer: Well, some people would
say that everything should be patented. The danger is that if you went that
far, you could actually slow the discovery process down. There are very good
theoretical reasons for thinking that market and property rights are the
ideal solution for dealing
with things, but there are also strong theoretical reasons for
thinking that in the realm of ideas, intellectual property rights are a
double-edged sword. You want to rely on them to some extent to get their
benefits, but you want to have a parallel, independent system and then
exploit the tension that’s created between the two. reason: What are those
theoretical reasons? Romer: It traces back to this
multiple use I was describing for ideas vs. single use for things. The miracle of the market system is that
for objects, especially transformed objects, there’s a single price which does two different jobs.
It creates an incentive for somebody to produce the right amount of a good,
and it allocates who it should go to. A farmer looks at the price of a bushel
of wheat and decides whether to plant wheat or plant corn. The price helps
motivate the production of wheat. On the other side, when a consumer has to
decide whether to buy bread or corn meal, the price allocates the wheat
between the different possible users. One price does both jobs, so you can just let the market
system create the price and everything works wonderfully. With ideas, you can’t get one price to do both
things. Let me give an extreme example. Oral rehydration therapy is one of
those few ideas which did actually jump immediately from science to consumer
benefit. It’s a simple scientific insight about how you can save the life of
a child who’s suffering from diarrhea. Literally millions of lives have been
saved with it. So what price should you charge people for using it? Because everybody can use the idea at the same
time, there’s no tragedy of the commons {droits
au sens de copyright, avoir le droit de} in the intellectual
sphere. There’s no problem of overuse or overgrazing or overfishing an idea.
If you give an idea away for free, you don’t get any of the problems when you
try and give objects away for free. So the efficient thing for society is to
offer really big rewards for some scientist who discovers an oral rehydration
therapy. But then as soon as we discover it, we give the idea away for free
to everybody throughout the world and explain “Just use this little mixture
of basically sugar and salt, put it in water, and feed that to a kid who’s
got diarrhea because if you give them pure water you’ll kill them.” So with
ideas, you have this tension: You want high prices to motivate discovery, but
you want low prices to achieve efficient widespread use. You can’t with a
single price achieve both, so if you push things into the market, you try to
compromise between those two, and it’s often an unhappy compromise. The government doesn’t pay drug companies prizes
for coming up with AIDS drugs. It says they’ve got to incur {supporter, engager} these huge expenses,
but then if they succeed, they can charge a high price for selling that drug.
This has generated a lot of progress and we’re prolonging the life of people
with AIDS, but the high price is also denying many people access to those
drugs. reason: Over the broad sweep of
human history, technological progress and economic growth were painfully
slow. Why has it sped up now? Romer: It’s so striking.
Evolution has not made us any smarter in the last 100,000 years. Why for
almost all of that time is there nothing going on, and then in the last 200
years things suddenly just
go nuts? One answer
is that the more people you’re around, the better off {à
l’aise, aisé, riche, I suppose. Plus on est de fous, plus on rit}
you’re going to be. This again traces back to the fundamental difference I
described before. If everything were just objects, like trees, then more people means there’s
less wood per person. But if somebody discovers an idea, everybody gets to use it, so the more
people you have who are potentially looking for ideas, the better off we’re
all going to be. And each time we made a little improvement in technology, we
could support a slightly larger population, and that led to more people who
could go out and discover some new technology. Another answer is that we developed better
institutions. Neither the
institutions of the market nor the institutions of science existed even as late
as the Middle Ages. Instead we had the feudal system, where peasants couldn’t
decide where to work and the lord couldn’t sell his land. On the science
side, we had alchemy. What did you do if you discovered anything? You kept it
secret. The last thing you’d do was tell anybody. reason: How did the better
institutions come about? Romer: That’s one of the deep
questions. There’s some kind of political process, some group decision
process, which leads to institutions. If you go back to what I said a minute
ago about the advantages of having many people, you can see that there’s a
tension here. There are huge benefits to having more people and having us all
interact amongst ourselves to
create goods and to share ideas. But you face a really big challenge
in trying to coordinate all of those decisions, because if you have large
numbers of independent decision makers who aren’t coordinating their actions
appropriately, you could get chaos. Think about millions of drivers with no rules of the road,
no agreement about whether you drive on the left or the right. So where do these institutions come from? It was a
process of discovery,
just as people discovered how to make bronze. They also discovered ways to
organize political life {naïf salaud}.
We can use democratic choice as an alternative to, say, a hereditary system
of selecting who’s the king. What’s subtle here is, How do those discoveries
get into action? It’s not like a profit motive in a firm that brings software to market.
There was a process of persuasion when somebody discovered that, hey, this
would be a better way for us to organize ourselves. So we had political and
economic thinkers — Locke, Hobbes, Smith — who managed to persuade some of
their peers to adopt those institutions. So institutions came from a combination of
discovery, persuasion, adoption — and then copying. When good institutions
work somewhere in the world, other places can copy them. reason: Many economic historians are
critical of New Growth Theory. Economic growth is a modern phenomenon, yet it
appears that New Growth Theory should apply equally to the Roman Empire or
Ming China as well as the modern world. Romer: I think that’s a
caricature of the theory. New Growth Theory describes what’s possible for us
but says very explicitly that if you don’t have the right institutions in
place, it won’t happen. If anything, it was the old style of theory which
made it sound like technological change falls from the sky like manna from
heaven, regardless of how we structure our institutions. This new theory says
technological change comes about if you have the right institutions, which we
have had. reason: So what’s the crucial
difference between Ming China and modern economies today? Romer: Ming China was very
advanced. It had steel. It had clocks. It had movable type. Yet it was far
from generating either the
modern institutions of science or the institutions of the market. The market and science differ in their treatment
of property rights, but they’re similar in that they rely on individuals who
are free to operate under essentially no constraints by authority or
tradition. It took a special set of historical circumstances to persuade
people that things could work if you freed people, within certain
institutional constraints, to pursue their own interests. This is where Ming
China was very far away from modern notions. Part of the answer to this big question about
human history has been the acceptance of relatively unfettered {sans entraves. Fettered, enchaîné}
freedom for large numbers of individuals. It’s something we just take for
granted, but if you described it in the abstract to the people of 50,000
years ago, they would never believe it could possibly work. They were conditioned
to systems where there was the head man or the chief, and as numbers got at
all large, there was a sense that you had to have somebody with kind of
dictatorial control. It was a deep philosophical insight and deep change in
the whole way we viewed the world to tolerate and accept and then truly
celebrate freedom. Freedom
may be the fundamental hinge {gond, pivot}
on which everything turns. reason: You often cite the
combinatorial explosion of ideas as the source of economic growth. What do
you mean by that? Romer: On any conceivable
horizon — I’ll say until about 5 billion years from now, when the sun
explodes — we’re not going to run out of discoveries. Just ask how many
things we could make by taking the elements from the periodic table and
mixing them together. There’s a simple mathematical calculation: It’s 10
followed by 30 zeros. In contrast, 10 followed by 19 zeros is about how much
time has elapsed since the universe was created. reason: Of all those billions of
combinations, the vast majority are probably going to be useless. So how do
you find the useful ones? Romer: This is why science and the market are so
important for this discovery process. It’s really important that we focus
our energy on those paths that look promising, because there are many more
dead ends out there than there are useful things to discover. You have to have systems which explore lots of
different paths, but then those systems have to rigorously shut off the ones
that aren’t paying off
and shift resources into directions which look more promising. The market does this
automatically. The institutions of science could tip either way. In
American science, we have vigorous competition between lots of different
universities, which leads to a kind of marketplace of ideas. You can think of
other institutions of science that aren’t nearly as competitive. In the
national laboratories, people are in the worst case civil servants: They’re
there for life, and there’s always more funding for them. reason: Does New Growth Theory
give us some new insights on how to think about monopolies? Romer: There was an old,
simplistic notion that monopoly was always bad. It was based on the realm of
objects — if you only have objects and you see somebody whose cost is
significantly lower than their price, it would be a good idea to break up the
monopoly and get competition to reign freely. So in the realm of things, of
physical objects, there is a theoretical justification for why you should
never tolerate monopoly. But in the realm of ideas, you have to have some
degree of monopoly power. There are some very important benefits from
monopoly, and there are some potential costs as well. What you have to do is
weigh the costs against the benefits. Unfortunately, that kind of balancing test is
sensitive to the specifics, so we don’t have general rules. Compare the costs
and benefits of copyrighting books versus the costs and benefits of patenting
the human genome. They’re just very different, so we have to create
institutions that can respond differentially in those cases. reason: You have written, “There
is absolutely no reason why we cannot have persistent growth as far into the
future as you can imagine.” Your Stanford colleague, the biologist Paul
Ehrlich, disagrees. He believes that economic growth is an unsustainable
cancer that is destroying the planet. How would you go about convincing
people like Ehrlich that they are wrong? Romer: Paul seems singularly
immune to being convinced. He has been on the wrong side of these issues, so
I wouldn’t set that as my standard of persuading anybody. However, if I took
a neutral observer who might listen to me and Paul, there’s a pretty easy way
to explain why I’m right and why Paul misunderstands. You have to define what
you mean by growth. If by growth you mean population, more people, then Paul
is actually right. There are physical limits on how many people you can have
on Earth. If we took peak population growth rates from the ‘70s at 2 percent
per year, you can only sustain that for a couple of hundred years before you
really run into true physical constraints. reason: I would remind you that
Ehrlich said that there would be billions of people dying of starvation in
the 1980s. Romer: He got the potentials
wrong and the time frame wrong, but it’s absolutely true that population
growth will have to come to zero at some point here on Earth. The only debate
is about when. Now, what do I mean when I say growth can
continue? I don’t mean growth in the number of people. I don’t even mean
growth in the number of physical objects, because you clearly can’t get
exponential growth in the amount of mass that each person controls. We’ve got
the same mass here on Earth that we had 100,000 years ago and we’re never
going to get any more of it. What I mean is growth in value, and the way you
create value is by taking that fixed quantity of mass and rearranging it from
a form that isn’t worth very much into a form that’s worth much more. A canonical example is turning
sand on the beach into semiconductors. reason: What do you make of the
recent protests against globalization? Romer: When we were describing
the broad sweep of human history, we talked about how hard it was for people
to get used to the idea
of freedom. There was another kind of adjustment that we had to make
as well: We had to get used to the idea of the market, and especially market exchange among
anonymous strangers. People often contrast this with the institutions of the
family, where you’ve got notions of sharing and mutual obligation. Many of us
have a deep psychological intuition rooted in our evolutionary history that
makes us feel warmly toward the family and suspicious of large, impersonal,
anonymous market exchange. I think that emotional impulse is part of what
some of the environmental ideologues draw on when they attack the whole
market system and corporations and modern science and everything. This is a case where human psychology that was
attuned to a hunter-gatherer environment is just a little bit out of touch
with a new world that’s much more interconnected, much more interactive, and
in many ways a much more satisfying and rich human experience. You can
idealize life in a hunter-gatherer society {mais
celle des Etats-Unis, vous pouvez aussi, c’est même recommandé si j’en juge
par l’interviewé}, but nobody wants to go through the frequent death
of a child — a very common experience for almost all of history that has been
reduced a phenomenal degree within human memory. reason: How would you convince
protestors of the benefits of globalization? Romer: First, just look at the facts. The protestors are amazingly ignorant
about what has happened in terms of, say, life expectancy. Life expectancy for people in
the poorest countries of the world is now better than life expectancy in
England when Malthus was so worried about it ♦.
Then you look at the variation of experience
between the poor countries that have done best and the ones that have done
worst, and try to see what the correlations are. Which countries did best?
Was it the countries that adopted the market most strongly, embraced foreign
investment, and tried to adopt property rights? Or was it the other countries? The evidence again is clear. One of the untold
stories about the ‘80s and ‘90s was the really dramatic turnaround in the developing
world that took place on this issue. If you track the legislative history on
foreign investment, you see a colonial legacy, even as late as the ‘70s,
where developing countries have laws designed to keep corporations out. Then
there’s this dramatic turnaround as they saw the benefits that a few key
economies received by inviting in foreign investment. It’s not the people
from the developing world who are making the argument that Nike is a threat
to their sovereignty or well-being. It’s people in the United States. The
people in the developing world understand pretty clearly where their
self-interest lies. reason: What about boosting
economic growth in developed countries? Romer: For Europe and the United
States, I think we need to be thinking very hard about how we can restructure
our institutions of science. How can we restructure our system of higher
education? How can we make sure that it has the benefits of vigorous
competition and free entry, especially of those bright young people who might
do really different kinds of things? We should not assume that we’ve already
got the ideal institutions and the only thing we need to do is just throw
more money at them. Unfortunately, I think a lot of countries have a
long way to go to catch up to the state where we are in the United States —
and I’m not that happy about where we are in the United States. Many European
countries simply have not recognized the power of competition between
institutions. So they have monolithic, state-run university systems. That
stifles competition between individual researchers and slows down the whole
innovative process. They also need to let people move more flexibly from the
university into the private sector and back. This is something that many
countries watching venture capital start-ups have become aware of, although
they’ve been slower to get their institutions to adjust. reason: In your recent paper on
doing R&D, you said you think it would be possible to raise the growth
rate from its average rate of 1.8 percent between 1870 and 1992 to 2.3
percent. Romer: Well, I was trying to set
a goal. When you’re thinking about the future, you never really know what
we’re going to discover, but I think there’s a reason to set for ourselves an
ambition of trying to raise the rate of growth by half a percent per year.
The United States achieved about 0.5 percent a year faster growth than the
U.K. did since 1870, so we’ve got a historical precedent for creating
institutions which lead to better innovation of the market and strengthen
science significantly. We should aim for that kind of improvement again. reason: Why would that be
important? Romer: As you accumulate these
growth rates over the decades, we get much higher levels of income. That lets
us deal more effectively with all the problems we face, whether it’s making
good on commitments to pay for people’s health care as they get older,
preserving more of the environment, or providing resources so that people can
have time to be out of the labor market for a certain period of time — when
they’re raising kids, say, or when they want to take an extended sabbatical. Income per capita in 2000 was about $36,000 in
year 2000 dollars. If real income per person grows at 1.8 percent per year,
by 2050 it will increase to $88,000 in year 2000 purchasing power. Not bad.
But if it grows at 2.3 percent per year, it will grow to about $113,000 in
year 2000 purchasing power. In today’s purchasing power, that extra $25,000
per person is equal to income per capita in 1984. So if we can make the choices
that increase the rate of growth or real income per person to 2.3 percent per
year, in 50 years we can get extra income per person equal to what in 1984 it
had taken us all of human history to achieve. One policy innovation, for example, that would boost
the growth rate would be to subsidize universities to train more
undergraduate and graduate students in science and engineering. Also, you
could give graduate students portable fellowships that they could use to pay
for training in any field of natural science and engineering at any
institution the students choose. Graduate students would no longer be hostage
to the sometimes parochial research interests of university professors.
Portable fellowships would encourage lab directors and professors to develop
programs that meet the research and career interests of the students. reason: What’s next in New Growth
Theory? Any conceptual breakthroughs on the horizon? Romer: Because the economics of
ideas are so different from the economics of markets, we’re going to have to
develop a richer understanding of non-market institutions, science-like
institutions. This is going to be a new endeavor for economics. reason: Do you think that there
is a big role for economic historians in helping uncover this richer theory? Romer: History is an absolutely
essential body of evidence, because you can’t make inferences about long-run
trends using year-to-year or quarter-to-quarter data. reason: There is a growing
movement against technological progress around the world. Why is there this
negative reaction to technological progress and what can we do about it? Romer: You’re a big believer in
turmoil and creative destruction when you’re early in life, because you can
knock down the old and create your new thing. Once you achieve a certain
level, you tend to get very conservative and try to slow the gales down,
because they might blow you over. So I think we have to seriously commit
ourselves to maintaining space for new entrants and for young people. That’s
one way to keep the process going. Another is to do what scholars have always
done: to proselytize, to dissect incoherent arguments. I think we’ll be able to maintain this dynamic of
progress that was unleashed a couple centuries ago. There will be small
setbacks and a lot of noise and complaining, but the opportunities and the
benefits are just too great to pull back. reason: Could anything stop
economic growth and technological progress? Romer: Even if one society loses
its nerve, there’ll be new entrants who can take up the torch and push ahead.
Mancur Olson talks about Caldwell’s Law, the idea that no nation has remained
truly innovative for very long. Look at Italy, and then Holland, and then the
U.K., and then the United States. The pessimistic interpretation is that nobody
can keep the process going. The optimistic interpretation is, Yes, you can,
but somebody else comes along and the progress moves from one place to the
next. We’ve seen individual societies where conservative
or reactionary elements suppress the changes. What has protected us in the
past is that there were other nations that could try new paths. You didn’t
have the same political dynamic everywhere at once. If in the far future we reach a situation where
there really is truly global political control — if multinational
institutions grow more powerful over economic affairs so that there is
imposed uniformity across all nations — then there’d be a loss of diversity.
And if the reactionary elements got in control of those institutions, there’d
be no room for the new entrant, the upstart, to adopt new ideas. But that’s a
pretty distant and unlikely prospect. |